Why private players choose to go it alone
The free-rider problem inhibits greater action
on environmental sustainability.
Altruism has not demonstrated enough power to
change this and societal shaming can backfire.
But there are other ways self-interest can be
harnessed to catalyse collective action, through positive, negative and
altruistic incentives.
ECONOMIC,
SOCIAL AND ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT ASSESSMENTS
I’ve completed
numerous economic, social and environmental impact assessments for clients.
Most recently, this included calculating and assessing the impact of a major Melbourne event (I won't reveal the client by name, for obvious reasons) on the local economy, society and environment.
Most of the
focus of this type of work is on the economic, rather than social or
environmental impact. It involves real numbers, as well as some more slightly abstract
assumptions and multipliers, and estimates the impact of specific expenditures
and investments on the broader economy.
Social
impact assessments are far more qualitative, usually based on stakeholder
consultation to compile ‘impressions’ and ‘feelings’ about the benefits certain
activities have on them and the local community.
Environmental
impact assessments are often a mix of both – quantitative assessment of the financial
implications of investment in environmental sustainability, and qualitative
commentary on how this might help change cultural norms relating to
sustainability.
THE FREE
RIDER PROBLEM
Environmental
sustainability is notoriously difficult to achieve because, as the economists
among us will understand all too well, it represents a public good with an
inherent free-rider problem. Take Australia for example. We contribute just 1%
to global CO2 emissions. Between 2000 and 2011, China alone was adding a new
‘Australia’ to world CO2 emissions every 7.5 months, and in 2011, it did so in
just 4.5 months! So any efforts by Australia to tackle global CO2 emissions alone
would be negligible[1].
This is the
free-rider problem of public goods – no individual can privately capture the
benefits of their own actions, nor exclude others from enjoying the benefits of
a cleaner general environment if they didn’t also contribute. So every player has
an incentive to ‘cheat’, letting others solve the problem without contributing
their own efforts for the greater good (because their individual contribution
matters so little). And when everyone acts on this incentive, nothing is
achieved.
ALTRUISM,
SOCIAL LICENSE OR SELF-INTEREST?
So why do
some private players, such as the organisers of the above Melbourne event, choose to take environmental action,
knowing their contribution is negligible? Is it:
·
Pure
self-interest to save costs over the longer term?
·
Guilt
and a desire to maintain a ‘social license’?
·
Genuine
altruistic concern for the environment and future generations?
Self-interest
can be powerful. This client for example, on one of its energy-saving investments, was
able to recover its entire expenditure on solar panels for one of its buildings in just over a single year. And
herein, future energy savings can be reinvested in the client's events, facilities and services, and in showcasing
Melbourne, Victoria and Australia to the world. And all this generates benefits
not just for the broader society, but benefits the client is able to individually
capture.
A desire to
maintain a ‘social license’ can also be effective. Given the power of
contemporary social media, if an entity misbehaves, a targeted campaign of
online shaming by just a small group of ‘social justice warriors’ can draw
widespread attention and compel the entity to toe the line. The online response
to Martin Shkreli’s decision to hike the price of an important AIDS drug from
$13.50 to $750 per pill is one good example of this.
Then of
course, there are the altruists who genuinely gain value from seeing a world
that is preserved for the use of others and for future generations. Any form of
community volunteerism could fall into this category, where individuals gain
nothing tangible for themselves, and wouldn’t likely be shamed for anonymously
not participating, but still choose to participate in something for the greater
good. Quite often, this is what motivates individuals within an organisation to
action. Working with the blessing, although not always the resources of the
organisation, it is a way to make a difference in the public realm for people
who are truly committed to a more environmentally sustainable future.
SHORTCOMINGS
AND THE PATH AHEAD
In terms of
‘social license’, many are starting to resent the kind of ‘mob justice’ where an
online minority have the power to destroy not just a company’s reputation and
consequent financial sustainability, but an individual’s entire livelihood. And
in an arena where facts are irrelevant and feelings reign supreme, the
punishment can easily outweigh the crime.
As for
altruism, if the previous centuries of global industrialisation have taught us
anything, it’s that altruism is not yet common or powerful enough to limit
environmental degradation in the face of rapidly advancing human living
standards.
So if
culture changes too slowly and societal shaming can backfire, incentives must
be changed another way. Which leaves us with the poster child of economics and
the bane of social advocates – self-interest. It must be in a person’s own
self-interest to contribute.
In a way, self-interest
contains scope for a combination of all three ‘incentives’ in driving
environmental sustainability – not just at the individual level, but the
national level. While positive incentives, such as subsidised solar panels,
have their role to play, psychology confirms negative incentives to be just as
(if not more) effective (the risk of ‘loss’ is a greater motivator than the
chance of ‘winning’). Emissions trading schemes for example, impose a cost on
polluters – a punishment for polluting and a cost-mitigation for complying, not
a reward for not polluting and no punishment for polluting.
Furthermore,
the ability to shame someone or something into compliance also represents a
form of self-interest in terms of the entity’s own desire to maintain its
social license.
And
finally, when people do good, they feel good. So self-interested environmental
sustainability can arguably foster altruistic-appearing behaviour too.
In my experience,
despite how crucial it is for long term economic development that the world
operates sustainably, the environmental component of these impact assessments
can often be something of an afterthought. But with the right incentives – be
they positive, negative or altruistic – they can become a focus of projects in
their own right.
[1] Calm down, this is not an argument
against Australia participating in climate change action, it is merely an
illustration of the free rider problem of public goods.
No comments:
Post a Comment