Auto Ads

Thursday 14 June 2018

Will the US please stop waging trade wars that they keep losing?

The trade war of the 1930s wasn’t the actual cause or main driver of the Great Depression.
But it still had immediate and long-term costs.
And just like today, the US got out-played by the rest of the world.

I recently listened to a lecture by Professor Jeff Borland of the University of Melbourne. The topic was What happened in the global trade war in the Great Depression? An historical perspective on Trump and tariffs. And two main points emerged from the discussion:
1.       The trade war of the 1930s wasn’t the actual cause or main driver of the Great Depression; and
2.       To the extent that you can actually do a trade war ‘right’, the US stuffed up that trade war too.

THE GOLD STANDARD
The Gold Standard – the international monetary system of the day – was the main cause of the Great Depression (as I’ve discussed previously). It was a truly destructive system, not only causing the Depression, but hindering any recovery and encouraging beggar-thy-neighbour trade and financial policies.
When the US started hording gold reserves during the ‘Roaring 20s’ (ironically as a hedge against future crises) rather than printing money to ‘sterilise’ these gold inflows, other countries followed suit (starting with France). Countries maintained high interest rates and refrained from printing money to keep inflation rates down and attract gold, so they didn’t run out of reserves in the face of this global rush for gold. This crippled global consumption and investment and drove global inflation rates into a deflationary spiral – now known as the Great Depression.
And to add insult to injury, the Gold Standard prevented exchange rates from adjusting to support an economic recovery. It also prevented countries from lowering interest rates and flooding their financial markets with liquidity to end the downward spiral because this would risk breaking their ‘pegging’. And internationally coordinated monetary stimulus and/or system-wide wage cuts to restore balance while preserving the Gold Standard proved to be administrative fantasies. So the downward spiral continued.
Countries were very hesitant to abandon the Gold Standard. Germany in particular, was especially paranoid of a repeat of its 1920s hyperinflation[1] and didn’t want to risk a depreciating exchange rate triggering another inflationary episode. So even upon the collapse of a major Austrian bank, and the ensuing financial crisis, Germany imposed tariffs and capital controls, rather than abandoning the Gold Standard. And these capital controls froze the assets of many European countries that had invested in Germany, thereby spreading the crisis to the rest of Europe.
Britain did abandon in September 1931 (countries that abandoned earliest tended to recover fastest and had the smallest falls – even modest increases – in imports from 1929-35). And this triggered other countries to either follow suit (including Australia and other Sterling Bloc countries), impose capital controls (including Uruguay, Greece, Czechoslovakia, Colombia and Iceland), or ratchet up their trade barriers even further (including France, Canada, South Africa, Germany, and the Netherlands) to offset Britain’s new competitive advantage (devaluation) without leaving the Gold Standard.
So this, rather than the trade war, was the main cause and driver of the Great Depression – countries not adhering to the rules of the international monetary system, and then stubbornly remaining within the confines of that system while in the midst of the crisis.

THE TRADE WAR
Paul Krugman wrote that economics’ ‘dirty little secret’ is that, while a trade war is unambiguously bad, we tend to oversell it.
Firstly, the Depression itself can actually be seen to have worsened the trade war, rather than the other way around. This is because tariffs were denominated in dollar terms, rather than percentage terms, and massive price deflation associated with the Depression caused these tariffs to rise in percentage terms, thereby automatically worsening the trade war. World trade did collapse during the Great Depression by 25-30%. But again, the collapse in trade was mostly driven by falling incomes associated with the Depression itself, rather than falling incomes being driven by the collapse in trade. In the US specifically, only about 10% of their reduction in imports was from the Smoot-Hawley Act that triggered the trade war; about 20% from the automatic deflation-induced tariff increases; and the remainder from Depression-driven falls in GDP.
I’ve also written previously about how the Depression was actually a driver of the trade war, rather than the other way around. Because of the above constraints of the Gold Standard, and the administrative obstacles to internationally coordinated monetary policy or system-wide wage cuts, tariffs and capital controls were seen as the only viable option to reflate the economy via price levels and import substitution.
And in terms of declines in actual GDP too, the trade war can’t really be attributed as a major cause. And today, with the advantage of flexible exchange rates and Central Banks and governments that should now know how to handle a downturn properly, a trade war is very unlikely to trigger a major downturn.

But this isn’t to say the trade war didn’t have significant costs in the 1930s, or that it wouldn’t today. The trade war certainly didn’t help, and still had many costs of its own.
Firstly, a major trade war causes countries to start producing what they formerly imported – goods and services in which they do not possess a comparative advantage. This restructuring of global supply chains is a seriously damaging disruption (think all the jobs lost in the transition towards free trade, but with losses in efficiency). And while demand that is choked off by tariffs and barriers can be largely replaced by demand for domestic produce, the distributional and efficiency losses accumulate over time. A trade war is very hard to unwind, free trade very hard to re-establish. And for all the years that trade barriers persist, these losses from having production in less efficient locations accumulate into significant amounts of lost output, productivity and innovation, well beyond when the trade war starts to unwind. Imagine how long it’ll take to unwind a modern trade war, and the subsequent cumulative losses.
And this isn’t even to mention the political ramifications. The Smoot-Hawley Act did have big impacts on some surrounding countries – Cuba lost an estimated 10% of its national income from the associated US sugar tariff! This no doubt contributed to the subsequent revolution and overthrow of Cuba’s pro-American government in 1933. No one can say this didn’t have very long-lasting consequences.
There’s also the potential for trade wars to develop into actual wars. Keynes noted the ability of free trade to create customers out of potential enemies, thereby facilitating world peace. Who would wage war on a trading partner? I mean, apart from Trump. And no doubt the breakdown of international trade in the 1930s made it all the easier for countries to go to war in WWII. Extensive losses of trade had already occurred. What more could be lost from war? I mean, apart from the obvious.
If WWII was good for anything, it reinforced the need for global cooperation to facilitate recoveries and trade. Trade wars undermine this.

THE US'S STUFF-UP
But what was particularly interesting was how inept the US was in the 1930s trade war too – just like today.
The Smoot-Hawley Act wasn’t a reaction to the Great Depression. It was imposed by the Republicans beforehand in 1929 and intended to protect the agricultural sector which had suffered in the 1920s. But the only agricultural products that had import competition were sugar and wool, which had enjoyed significant tariff protection for decades. More effective agricultural protection would have been subsidies, not tariffs. Furthermore, the Act increased manufacturing tariffs more than agricultural tariffs anyway. This included coal and lumber, which were actually agricultural inputs. This means tariffs on these products actually hindered agriculture to such an extent that the ‘effective’ rate of protection on agriculture from Smoot-Hawley was actually negative.
The Act ended up imposing significant tariff increases on hundreds on imported goods. Smoot himself even used the Act as an excuse to limit the import of what he saw as ‘obscene material’. A news article at the time used the heading “Smoot smites smut”. This should serve as a dire (though still amusing) warning of how easily fondness for protectionism can spread beyond initial intentions.
It is also very similar to what is happening today – US tariffs will save around 26,280 steel and aluminium-producing jobs, while costing 432,747 jobs elsewhere, including industries that use these materials as inputs (such as the car industry).
Both times the US started a trade war. And both times, the US shot themselves in the foot with their first attempt.
What is also similar is the reaction of the rest of the world. Today, the EU, Canada and other countries are retaliating with tariffs on, among other things, Kentucky bourbon, Iowa pork, Wisconsin motorcycles, and Ohio washing machines – key exports, from states that voted for Trump in 2016. China too, is going after US industries with powerful lobby groups that are most likely to successfully pressure Trump into backing down. So while the US is shooting itself in the foot, the rest of the world is expertly attacking Trump’s own base, while leaving themselves plenty of alternative suppliers of such goods.
Similarly in the 1930s, retaliation against Smoot-Hawley came from Canada, Britain and Europe, not in the form of general tariff increases, but in US-specific attacks. Britain increased tariffs on US imports, while decreasing tariffs on imports from its colonies (a policy called Imperial Preference). This offset the losses to itself while maximising the impacts on the US. Europe, while not explicitly raising tariffs on the US exclusively (which would have breached ‘most favoured nation’ rules), did raise tariffs on specific goods which mostly came from the US – so the effect was the same.
So, whereas the US actually worsened protection of agriculture and triggered a trade war, the rest of the world was far more direct and effective in its attacks on the US – and the US still gets the blame for starting it all.

DON'T START A TRADE WAR!
I suppose it’s not surprising that the ‘winners’ in a trade war are the second movers. When the rest of the world has a single country to blame for starting it, it’s much easier for them to gang up on the single country than for the single country (even one as big as the US) to beat the rest of the world.
It’s one thing to ignore economists when we warn you against starting a trade war. It’s quite another to ignore us when we’re actually telling you how to fight it better.


[1] After WWI, the Treaty of Versailles imposed massive war reparations on Germany, which it consequently paid by simply printing massive amounts of its own currency, driving its inflation rate up to 72.6 trillion percent! The US dollar went from buying 0.2-0.25 Mark to 4-5 trillion Mark. There were stories of people in Germany carrying wheelbarrows full of cash to buy a loaf of bread, getting mugged for the wheelbarrow instead of the cash.

No comments:

Post a Comment