Theo J Vystadt is an economic and political commentator. He investigates and discusses major national and international issues and events through the lens of economics.
Auto Ads
Saturday, 1 December 2018
Sunday, 11 November 2018
US Hawks vs NZ Doves.
Here is a link
to a brief that I wrote for the Housing Industry Association. Below is an
extended version.
New Zealand’s
apparent willingness to accept higher inflation than the US could come in handy
in the next downturn.
Terminology time! An inflation ‘hawk’ is a person who is
more worried about inflation getting too high. An inflation ‘dove’ is someone
more worried about inflation getting too low.
The US and New Zealand demonstrate both these positions
quite well.
The US is increasing interest rates while inflation barely
touches their target of 2%. Understandable – they slashed interest rates so
dramatically in the GFC and have remained so low for so long that they’re no
doubt eager to bring them back up, lest they spur some unintended imbalances,
like an over-inflated stock market or housing bubble. Still though, hawkish.
In NZ however, recent economic data is pointing to strength
– stronger economic growth, decade-low unemployment now at just 3.9%, and
employment and inflation expected to overshoot their targets on a sustained
basis. Inflation is still currently in the middle of their 1-3% target, but
given this strong data, you’d think they’d upgrade their intentions for future
interest rates rises. On the contrary, they’re being quite dovish about it.
They’re intent on keeping interest rates where they are until mid-2020 (the
same intention they had before this new stronger data came out).
As Westpac’s Dominick Stephens said:
“RBNZ
recognises that inflation pressures have built. The inflation forecast was
lifted, upside risks to inflation were emphasised more heavily, and rising
inflation was discussed up front in the document. Intriguingly, the forecast
was for inflation to rise above [their target] 2% in the medium term. [But]
RBNZ has declined to alter its [cash rate] forecast … They’re choosing
higher inflation rather than a higher [cash rate]”.
There has been commentary for several years, including from
Nobel Prize-winning economist Paul Krugman, that advanced economy central banks
may have set their inflation targets too low – the US and UK at 2%, the EU under
2%, Australia 2-3%, NZ 1-3%. Again, understandable. They were set in the 1990s,
with the high inflation of the 1970s and 80s still fresh in policymakers’
minds. So they were extra keen to keep inflation under control, and believed a
1-3% buffer above zero would be enough to prevent self-fulfilling deflation
during any downturn (which can actually be just as bad and just as hard to fix
as high inflation – if not more so).
The GFC however, demonstrated that inflation can indeed,
still get too close to zero – and lower. Current inflation buffers have not
negated the dreaded ‘liquidity trap’, where central banks have already dropped
interest rates to zero but, because of inadequate inflation, real
interest rates (the gap between interest rates and inflation) are still not low
enough, making monetary policy impotent to help recover the economy.
Consequently, many advanced economies undershot their inflation targets for
most of the last decade. It turns out, even getting close to deflation –
let alone actually achieving it – can be hard to reverse.
If however, inflation targets were increased to, say, 3-5%,
that would provide a bigger buffer, without inflation getting out of control.
Another way to look at it is that the risks of central bank policy are asymmetric:
the costs of allowing inflation to venture a little too high right now are far
smaller than the risks of increasing interest rates too fast and driving the
economy back into a liquidity trap or worse, a deflationary spiral.
Perhaps this is what NZ’s central bank is thinking – an
upwards reset of their 1-3% target so they have more inflationary ammunition in
the next downturn.
Take the following hypothetical example of what NZ
and the US could be facing soon.
The US is raising interest rates rapidly to keep their
inflation rate no higher than 2%. NZ however, is raising their interest rates
more slowly, willing to accept higher inflation of, say, 4%. This means that
the real interest rate remains much lower in NZ, actually below zero and
declining for most of this period – much more stimulatory for the economy.
Therefore, in almost two years, inflation is much higher in NZ and interest
rates much lower; and in the US, inflation is much lower and interest rates
much higher.
Then in two years, where I have assumed a significant global
downturn, both the US and NZ drop their interest rates back down to zero. It
would appear the US is in a better position – they were able to drop rates a
full 5%, NZ only 2.25%. NZ however, had a much higher inflation rate beforehand
that only falls to 2%, whereas the US’s 2% inflation rate falls back to 0%.
Which means upon the downturn, NZ’s real interest rate becomes -2% and the US’s
just 0%.
This would leave the US dealing with a ‘liquidity trap’
situation. Whereas in NZ, investment would still be preferable to holding cash,
so ongoing investment in NZ would act to stabilise the economy during the
downturn. In the US, the prospect of deflation would create a disincentive to
invest[1]
and the lack of investment would be an additional headwind exacerbating the
downturn.
So even though the US can drop interest rates more
dramatically upon the downturn, NZ is able to achieve a lower real
interest rate (even though it barely decreased in the last month) and
therefore, undertake stronger stimulus – because they allowed their inflation
rate to rise further beforehand, rather than rushing to increase interest
rates.
While these numbers are somewhat arbitrary, it does
illustrate that it’s not the size of the interest rate cut you have up your
sleeve. It’s the stimulatory effect of your interest rate position after the
cut has been made – the real interest rate. 0% interest rates with 2%
inflation is more stimulatory than 0% interest rates with 0% inflation.
Furthermore, in the former case of 2% inflation, people are also less worried
about self-fulfilling deflation[2].
The implications if Australia’s Reserve Bank similarly chose
to run the economy hotter for longer are clear for the housing industry. Lower
interest rates for longer will support mortgage holders and investors alike,
thereby supporting one of Australia’s most significant industries, even in the
face of the current housing downturn.
I know all of this sounds like a bit hypothetical and
abstract. But remember, psychology is very important in economics. The
perception of being too close to deflationary territory can, all by itself,
cause an economy to fall into deflationary territory. And the housing industry,
through the mortgage market, can be the hardest hit in such an event. That’s
why an arbitrary buffer sufficiently above 0% inflation is so important.
Because perception very much becomes reality.
[1] Not
just business investment in things like property, buildings, equipment,
machinery and staff, but also household investment in property, appliances, furniture,
vehicles, etc. Even government, upon the deflationary expectation that things
will be cheaper (or at least not much more expensive) in the future, may be tempted
to put off major infrastructure investments.
[2] And
as for the unintended consequences of prolonged low interest rates, like
financial instability – interest rates are not a good tool for reigning in
asset markets, especially if they are running in the opposite direction to the
real economy (as was the case in Australia until recently with booming housing
markets). This is more a job of macro-prudential regulation and oversight, by
the central bank and/or other regulators (like APRA and ASIC in Australia). Interest
rates should be the tool used to manage the real – not financial – economy.
Saturday, 27 October 2018
The hangover.
As predicted, US soybean exports surged last quarter in an effort to beat Chinese
retaliation to Trump’s trade war (artificially inflating economic growth
figures), and have now plummeted 97% as a result.
China is weaning themselves off US soybeans, consistent with the broader global trend away
from the US.
Combined with the ongoing drag of Trump’s trade war and the
inevitable weakening of the impact of Trump’s spending spree, the US’s current
binge can’t go on much longer. The hangover is coming.
Sayonara, America!
Just as predicted, while Trump continues his trade war, the rest of the world continues to move on
without him.
This time … fierce rivals China and Japan.
China, Japan Vow to Cooperate as Trump Hits
Both on Trade
By Isabel Reynolds and Emi Nobuhiro
26 October 2018 12:50 PM AEDT Updated on 26 October 2018 11:07 PM AEDT
By Isabel Reynolds and Emi Nobuhiro
26 October 2018 12:50 PM AEDT Updated on 26 October 2018 11:07 PM AEDT
China and Japan
capped a restoration of ties with agreements on everything from currency swaps
to ocean rescue Friday, a thaw that comes as President Donald Trump seeks
better trade terms with both nations.
Shinzo Abe
became the first Japanese prime minister to pay an official visit to China in
seven years, as Asia’s two largest economies sought to play down disagreements
that have hindered relations for decades. They both reiterated support for free
trade and called for the early conclusion of a regional trade pact with 16
Asia-Pacific nations that doesn’t include the U.S.
After Abe and
Chinese Premier Li Keqiang commemorated the 40th anniversary of a peace and
friendship treaty on Thursday, the two held formal talks on Friday and oversaw
the signing of cooperation agreements between the two governments. Abe then met
and dined with President Xi Jinping, marking a new high point for a
relationship he has long sought to mend.
At that
meeting, Xi said the two countries are becoming increasingly interdependent and
that they should be partners rather than threats to each other, according to a
Japanese official. He also said China’s Belt and Road initiative provides a
platform for cooperation and that the nations will adhere to free trade and
face global challenges together.
Abe was
accompanied to China by foreign and trade ministers and a 500-strong business
delegation. The two sides signed 50 cooperation agreements, including reviving
a 200 billion yuan ($29 billion) currency-swap deal. The neighbors also agreed
to discuss establishing a clearing bank for offshore yuan and cooperation
between Japan’s Financial Services Agency and the China Securities
“China is
willing to work together with Japan to take Sino-Japanese relations back to a
normal track, maintaining stable, sustainable and healthy development and
making new progress,” Li said during an appearance with Abe on Friday. Both
sides believed that stable relations were important and that they should take
“concrete measures” to become cooperative partners, he said.
Japan’s
relations with its biggest trading partner turned hostile in 2012, when it
nationalized part of a disputed East China Sea island chain, sparking sometimes
violent protests and damaging business ties. Since taking office at the end of
that year, Abe has consistently sought meetings with Chinese leaders, even as
anger simmered over the territorial and other disputes.
Abe said he
sought frank talks with Xi and Li covering North Korea and trade issues. The
two sides also agreed to cooperate on search-and-rescue operations at sea, and
assist each other in developing health care and elderly care services.
In a speech to
a business forum on Friday, Abe harked back to Japan’s role in providing aid
and private sector investment from the 1980s that helped turn China into an
economic powerhouse.
“The Japanese
government and companies invested and worked with the Chinese people toward
modernization,” he said. “Seeing how China has developed is a source of pride
for Japan as well.”
The thorniest
issues between the two sides had so far received little mention. There were no
immediate agreements on how to handle the territorial dispute, or the issue of
gas resources around the disputed sea border between their exclusive economic
zones.
“The difficult
issues are going to stay,” said Akio Takahara, a professor at the University of
Tokyo, adding that he expected relations to remain cordial at least until Xi
visits Japan, which he is expected to do for the Group of 20 summit in Osaka
next year.
“The Chinese
Communist Party always has this history card against Japan in their pocket,”
Takahara said. “Whenever they feel the need to take it out, I’m sure they will
do that.”
What do you do when your argument can't stand on its own?
Interesting article by Catherine Rampell about how
Republicans, instead of attempting to defend their policies on their own merit,
are simply lying about what they want to achieve. With regard to health care
for example, Republicans have long desired (and attempted) Obamacare’s destruction.
But instead of trying to justify this position, they actually claim they’re
trying to do the exact opposite:
“For instance,
they might argue that in their ideal capitalist society, it’s not government’s
job to shield Americans from the financial risks of serious health conditions.
Every man (or woman) is an island, responsible for his or her own health care.
If expensive illnesses befall some unlucky members of society, and they lacked
the foresight or haven’t saved enough to plan for this risk on their own, then
too bad. Life ain’t fair.” Catherine Rampell
But instead of doing this, Republicans still maintain that
they want to do things like protect those with pre-existing conditions, despite
continued efforts to the contrary.
I made essentially the same point about Trumpcare last September.
“If Republicans
actually justified Trumpcare by saying that health care is not the role of
government, but the responsibility of the individual, and that the risk of
sickness, bankruptcy and death that comes from this is the inevitable price we
should pay for our 'freedom', then I could respect it.
I wouldn't
agree with it. Both socially and economically, public health care makes sense.
But at least their policy narrative would be consistent with their ideology.
But from
beginning to end, Republicans have claimed that Trumpcare will provide BETTER
health care to MORE people at LOWER cost, when so much evidence (including the
CBO and the insurance industry itself) seems to suggest WORSE, LESS and HIGHER.
So are they
being dishonest about their ideology or ignorant about their policy?”
Catherine Rampell thinks the former.
Republicans are mischaracterizing nearly all
their major policies. Why?
By Catherine Rampell
October 25 at 6:45 PM
By Catherine Rampell
October 25 at 6:45 PM
Republicans
have mischaracterized just about every major policy on their agenda. The
question is why. If they genuinely believe their policies are correct, why not
defend them on the merits?
Consider the
GOP tax cuts. Last year, Republicans said their bill would primarily benefit
the middle class, pay for itself and raise President Trump’s taxes, among other
claims.
Not one of
these contentions is remotely true.
A more honest
defense — and one occasionally revealed via accidentally-told-the-truth Kinsley
gaffes — might have been something like: We want to let rich people keep more
of their money, regardless of the cost to Uncle Sam. We want this both because
we (unlike most of the public) think that’s fair, and also because our donors
are demanding a return on their investment in us. Plus, maybe it’s a good thing
to reduce government revenue; that gives us motivation to “starve the beast” and
cut the safety net, which we think is a drag on the economy that protects
people from the consequences of their poor life choices.
Likewise with
family separations, a policy Trump is considering reviving.
In the spring,
the administration systematically ripped immigrant children from their mothers’
breasts with no plan for tracking where they ended up or how to reunite these
families. The rationale, as gaffingly revealed by White House Chief of Staff John
F. Kelly, was that such cruelty would deter asylum seekers.
But when voters
recoiled, the administration explained things differently. Officials
alternately lied that the policy was designed to help children, was actually a
Democratic policy or didn’t exist at all.
Lately, the
biggest GOP lies involve health care — the top midterm issue for voters — and
especially how Republicans would treat Americans with costly medical issues.
The public has
had ample opportunity to learn where Republicans stand on protections for those
with preexisting conditions. The party spent the past eight years, after all,
trying to repeal the Affordable Care Act, including these particular (very
popular) provisions.
And while
Republicans failed to repeal Obamacare legislatively, they’ve found other means
to undermine its protections.
For instance,
the Trump administration has expanded the availability of junk insurance. These
cheap plans look like regular insurance but actually cover little to no care,
something you would notice only if you read the fine print. Such policies are
not required to accept enrollees with preexisting conditions or to pay claims
related to preexisting conditions — even if the preexisting illness hadn’t even
been diagnosed at the time of enrollment.
These policies
threaten coverage another way, too. Because they siphon young, cheap and
healthy people off the Obamacare exchanges, they drive up prices on (real)
insurance and thereby put coverage further out of reach for people who are
sicker and older.
On Monday, the
administration issued new regulatory guidance that will effectively allow
states to nudge more people into these junk plans. And that’s just one of many
measures the administration has taken that will destabilize the individual
marketplaces and jack up unsubsidized premiums for people with preexisting conditions.
There’s clearly
appetite among state-level Republicans to roll back such protections, too.
In fact, 20 red
states have sued the federal government, arguing that Obamacare, including its
preexisting-condition protections, is unconstitutional. Administrations are
supposed to defend laws passed by Congress, but on these provisions, the Trump
administration has refused.
And yet, Trump
continues to argue that “Republicans will totally protect people with
Pre-Existing Conditions, Democrats will not!”
When Trump made
this claim at a rally in Wisconsin, he was echoed by Gov. Scott Walker (R), who
urged the crowd: “Don’t believe the lies. We will cover people with preexisting
conditions.”
This despite
the fact that Walker authorized his own attorney general to join that 20-state
lawsuit. But Walker is far from alone. Across the country, Republican
politicians shamelessly conceal their track record on this issue.
Once again,
rather than misrepresenting their own positions, Republicans could try to
defend them on the merits.
For instance,
they might argue that in their ideal capitalist society, it’s not government’s
job to shield Americans from the financial risks of serious health conditions.
Every man (or woman) is an island, responsible for his or her own health care.
If expensive illnesses befall some unlucky members of society, and they lacked
the foresight or haven’t saved enough to plan for this risk on their own, then
too bad. Life ain’t fair.
You might
wonder if maybe Republican politicians are mischaracterizing so many of their
own positions because they don’t fully understand them. But given that
Republican leaders have occasionally blurted out their true motives — on taxes,
immigration and, yes, even health care — this explanation seems a little too
charitable.
Republican
politicians aren’t too dumb to know what their policies do. But clearly they
think the rest of us are.
Sunday, 30 September 2018
The Impossible Trinity
No nation can
simultaneously achieve low taxes, easy business conditions, and low inequality.
There are plenty of valid middle-ground combinations.
But a free market with a large social safety net (high taxes + easy business conditions) appears more effective at tackling inequality than a command economy (low taxes + stringent business regulations).
There are plenty of valid middle-ground combinations.
But a free market with a large social safety net (high taxes + easy business conditions) appears more effective at tackling inequality than a command economy (low taxes + stringent business regulations).
I’ve written before about how globalisation has actually been a spectacular success.
It has generated monumental amounts of wealth, drastically reduced poverty, and
fostered international relations. Consequently, the solution to rising
inequalities in the developed world is not a retreat from globalisation. It is to
more fairly share its benefits through the tax system – social welfare,
infrastructure, education, health care, etc.
But there is another option – regulation. Instead of
tackling inequality through higher taxes and a greater redistributive role of
government, regulating business could reign in monopoly and monopsony power[1].
This would allow workers to share more in corporate success, thereby reducing
inequality[2].
Theoretically, unions are supposed to facilitate this too, which can also be
aided through regulation. Maybe businesses can also be regulated to provide
more things like health insurance, education and training, and salary insurance
to their workers. Mechanisms like ‘developer contribution plans’ even force the
private sector to contribute to infrastructure like public transport – all of
which would help address inequality.
And through this thought, I may have discovered something
interesting – what I’m dubbing The Impossible Trinity of Inequality[3].
My hypothesis – it’s impossible to simultaneously achieve low
taxes, easy business conditions, and low inequality:
·
If you want to go the capitalist route (easy
business conditions and low taxes), you have to accept that there will be a
high level of inequality, as those that are disadvantaged or simply unlucky in
their employment or health fortunes, won’t receive the support they need;
·
If you want to have low inequality but easy
business conditions, you have to have high taxes for the government to perform
its redistributive role; and
·
If you want to have low inequality but low taxes,
you have to have stringent business regulations that protect workers from
exploitation and support social mobility.
The evidence?
I previously wrote of the link between income inequality and
government tax revenue. An intuitive enough link – governments that collect
more taxes can undertake a greater redistributive role (social welfare,
infrastructure, education, health, etc.), resulting in lower rates of
inequality.
The following graph illustrates this for the OECD countries,
with surprising statistical accuracy (0.59 is actually a pretty good
correlation).
This time though, I combined an index of ‘ease of doing
business’ with tax revenue as a percentage of GDP. A lower value of this
combined index indicates lower taxes and easier business conditions. The
relationship is weaker, but still there, especially at the extremes. Countries
with the lowest taxes and easiest business conditions tended to have the
highest inequality. And those with the
highest taxes and most stringent business conditions tended to have the lowest
inequality.
And most importantly, not a single country in the OECD was
able to achieve the Impossible Trinity. No country simultaneously had low
taxes, easy business conditions and low inequality (three green boxes below).
Some countries couldn’t even achieve two – Mexico, Chile and
Turkey all enjoy low taxes, but stringent business conditions and high
inequality. And Belgium, while achieving low inequality, achieved it at the
cost of both high taxes and stringent business conditions.
But Norway and Denmark achieved both low inequality and easy
business conditions only at the cost of high taxes. The US chose another
trade-off – easy business conditions and low taxes at the cost of high
inequality.
Korea was perhaps the only major success-story outlier – it
achieved low taxes and easy business conditions at the cost of only moderate
inequality.
Several countries also chose a successful middle ground:
·
Australia and Switzerland enjoy low taxes with
average business conditions and average inequality;
·
The Czech Republic, the Slovak Republic,
Slovenia and Iceland achieved low inequality with average business conditions
and average taxes;
·
Estonia enjoys easy business conditions with
average taxes and average inequality; and
·
Canada, Ireland, the Netherlands, Poland,
Portugal, Spain and Germany were around average on all three indicators.
It’s worth noting though that no country was able to use
stringent business regulations to achieve low inequality and low taxes. This
was contrary to one of my above hypotheses. And it possibly suggests that
heavily regulating businesses is not as effective at tackling inequality as
high taxes and redistribution efforts. This is perhaps unsurprising. Income
redistribution puts resources (and therefore, choice) in the hands of
individuals. This is arguably more effective at helping those individuals than
regulation, which requires the government to attempt to decide what is best for
the individual.
Of course, these relationships aren’t perfect. And there are several different ways this data could have been sliced and diced. Further research could also yield the importance of personal vs. corporate tax rates. But this is a blog, not a submission to the Nobel Prize Committee. So for these purposes, I will still conclude thusly:
Of course, these relationships aren’t perfect. And there are several different ways this data could have been sliced and diced. Further research could also yield the importance of personal vs. corporate tax rates. But this is a blog, not a submission to the Nobel Prize Committee. So for these purposes, I will still conclude thusly:
·
You can’t achieve all three – it is indeed an
Impossible Trinity;
·
There are also plenty of valid middle-ground
combinations;
·
But a free market with a large social safety net
(high taxes + easy business conditions) like Norway and Denmark appears more
effective at tackling inequality than a command economy (low taxes + stringent
business regulations).
Task for humanity – can we turn it into The Possible
Trinity? Can we provide for everyone in society without the need for high taxes
or stringent regulations? An altruistic capitalist society, if you will.
*laughter*
[1]
The ability of businesses to control not just the price of the products they
sell, but also the price of the labour they buy.
[2] It
would also help address the ‘two-speed economy’ between corporate (and
therefore, asset market) success, and wage growth, thereby making the job of
Central Banks easier.
[3] I
first heard this expression when it referred to the Impossible Trinity of Central
Banking – the idea that an economy could not simultaneously achieve a fixed
exchange rate, open capital markets, and a Central Bank policy that targets
internal stability.
Wednesday, 26 September 2018
International trade is not a prisoners’ dilemma – cheating is how you lose.
The final sentence of this article poses a question: “Why, when America
is acting outside the rule book, should others stick to it?”
This is a dangerous thing for The Economist – formerly a
champion of free trade and State inaction – to say.
Firstly, China itself is definitely not innocent of playing
outside the rule book – think counterfeited US luxury goods, bootlegged Hollywood films, fake Apple stores, trade secrets pilfered from cutting edge US tech companies, forcing US firms to hand over their technology if they wanted to operate in China. But as I’ve made clear before,
the solution was never to trigger a trade war, but to create a coalition of
trading partners that would put pressure on China to behave better – something
like the TPP that Trump abandoned. This would have been far more likely to
generate cooperation rather than escalation.
Now to the question of why we should all keep playing by the
rules if one or two players have already started cheating. This is the common
misconception about world trade, and exactly how to trigger escalation and cause
everything to get worse.
Game theory has a scenario called the ‘prisoners’ dilemma’,
where two arrested criminals have the choice to ‘rat out’ one another, or
remain silent. Here are the possible outcomes:
·
Both stay silent, and only get 1 year in prison
for a lesser crime;
·
Only one criminal ‘rats’, resulting in the ‘rat’
going free and the one who remained silent getting 5 years in prison; or
·
Both criminals ‘rat’, resulting in both going to
prison for 3 years (less than the 5 years because they cooperated).
So even though the best outcome for both of the criminals combined
is to stay silent, the incentive for each criminal, no matter what the other
one does, is to ‘rat’:
·
If you assume your partner will stay silent, you
will go free by ‘ratting’;
·
If you assume your partner will ‘rat’, you also ‘ratting’
will give you a lesser prison term than staying silent.
Criminal 2
|
|||
Stay Silent
|
Rat
|
||
Criminal 1
|
Stay Silent
|
1,1
|
5,0
|
Rat
|
0,5
|
3,3
|
Applying this logic to international trade, we could say
that the optimal outcome is for everyone to cooperate (free trade), but that
everyone has an incentive to cheat, always, especially if someone has already
broken the rules.
But this is wrong.
During a trade war, retaliation (cheating in response to
someone else cheating) causes a worse outcome for everyone, including the ‘justified’ retaliator, as follows (the
numbers are arbitrary, but think of them as percentage changes in your country’s
GDP):
Country 2
|
|||
Cooperate
|
Cheat
|
||
Country 1
|
Cooperate
|
10,10
|
7,12
|
Cheat
|
12,7
|
5,5
|
·
Both countries gain 10% in GDP by trading
freely;
·
If one country imposes tariffs, they gain 12%
while the other still gains, but only 7%;
·
If both country’s cheat, they both only gain 5%.
So in international trade, even when your partners cheat, it
is still in your best interests to be able to import freely. Escalating a trade
war is never rational, even if it means swallowing a little pride.
Furthermore, the above example assumes that a country like
the US can benefit from being the only one who imposes tariffs because of their
size and market power. But as the steel and aluminium tariffs demonstrated,
even in a country with the US’s market power, such poorly targeted tariffs
damaged US companies that use steel and aluminium as inputs (e.g. the auto
industry) far more than it helped steel and aluminium producers (by an
estimated factor of 16:1!).
So the incentive to cheat is even more questionable, even if you can get away
with it.
So this is not the traditional ‘prisoners’ dilemma’ – yes, we
are better off cooperating, and if we have any market power, we do have an
incentive to cheat, just like the traditional game. BUT, the costs of the
escalation of a trade war rapidly increase as more players cheat, meaning that
it was better to just deal with one cheater than many.
In other words:
·
Both sides combined are better off cooperating (like
the prisoners’ dilemma);
·
If you assume your trade partner will cooperate,
you may have an incentive to cheat (like the prisoners’ dilemma);
·
But if you assume your trade partner will cheat,
you are better off not escalating and
instead, cooperating (unlike the prisoners’
dilemma).
As I wrote before about retaliating to Trump’s tariffs, we should have left it.
Saturday, 15 September 2018
The collapse of Lehman Brothers and the subsequent GFC.
10 years on we need to get the public on board with how policymakers responded.
As I’ve written before, the GFC was first and foremost an economic problem, and
a moral problem second. During the initial panic, and early in the recovery,
the economic problem must be dealt with first – emergency liquidity, targeted
bailouts, rock bottom interest rates, fiscal stimulus. THEN, once the economy
is on solid-footing again, the moral problem can be addressed – debt reduction,
financial regulation and oversight, and retribution against those responsible
can take place[1].
By and large, addressing the economic problem first is what
the US Federal Reserve and Government did. Consequently, unemployment peaked at
10% and the actual recession was short-lived. But there were subsequent
failures – both economic and moral. The fiscal support was short-lived and
inadequate, so the recovery took much longer than it should have. Furthermore,
financial sector reform – while things like the Dodd-Frank Act were a good
start – arguably didn’t go far enough to prevent a future crisis. And
importantly – and what most public opinion truly despised – virtually no one in
the financial sector was held accountable for the GFC. All the public saw was
bailouts, and bad people getting golden parachutes.
Consequently, despite the absolute necessity of these
emergency measures to stave off a much larger crisis (Depression 2.0), public opinion
now is very unfavourable to doing these things again if the occasion calls for
it.
But we can see what happens if policy is impotent during
such a crisis. The Great Depression was a great example – Central Banks obsessed
with maintaining their exchange rates relative to the Gold Standard, resulting
in higher interest rates, inadequate crisis liquidity and consequently, total financial
system collapse, Depression and widespread deflation, and 25% unemployment in
the US.
And following the GFC, Europe offers another case study of
policy impotence. The European Central Bank was slower to react in monetary
terms, more punitive measures were imposed against the banks, and governments reacted
in the reverse direction in fiscal terms with austerity. Consequently,
prolonged recession and deflation, and mass unemployment ensued, comparable
(even worse) than the Great Depression. One of the only silver linings was
Europe having a much more supportive social safety net this time around
compared to the Great Depression. So the human suffering and hardship could still have been worse.
As I’ve also mentioned before, public opinion matters. It’s not enough to say
that, as long as the right people are in power, they will do the right thing,
regardless of what ‘Joe Public’ thinks. I mean, Ben Bernanke faced scorched-earth
opposition to his crisis measures, but he still undertook them. But this is not
enough. Because if ‘Joe Public’ disapproves this time around, he will vote
accordingly, and during the next crisis we may see completely different types
in power. And that’s what we’ve seen. Following the GFC, a global wave of populism
has swept Europe, the US and even Australia. Brexit and Trump are merely the
most high-profile examples of this. But one of the telling characteristics of
such populism is a distrust of technical expertise – precisely the expertise
that is more likely to make the right decisions even when they are unpopular.
And if another crisis comes along (look out, Australia), and these new
populist powers refuse to provide the necessary (and often unpopular) support
because they find it simply unacceptable to bail out the financial sector
again, we are in trouble.
The public needs to be shown how these tough decisions were
the right ones. Yes, a lot more could have been done to speed up the recovery
(or in the case of Europe, not make things worse), reign in the financial
sector and punish those responsible. But if these new populist powers encounter
another crisis, and insist on addressing the morality issue before the economic
one, they will literally make the situation worse, especially for those they
claim to want to protect. And there will be no guarantee that those responsible
for the crisis in the first place will be caught up in the downward spiral.
Policymakers need to be able to quickly do the right thing without
having to justify it to politicians or the public. But once the dust settles, they
need to convince the public it was the right thing – before the time comes to do
the right thing again.
It’s always tempting to want to teach the bad guys a lesson –
but not at the expense of the rest of us.
Also see Catherine Rampell’s piece, Heaven help us in the next financial crisis.
[1] Technically,
as long as it doesn’t restart a panic and/or jeopardise the subsequent
recovery, regulation, oversight and retribution may begin sooner. But not debt
reduction.
Look who have just become friends.
Many, including myself, have said that Trump’s alienation of allies risks undermining Western alliances and creating a void that someone else will inevitably fill.
And look who have just become friends. China and Russia are:
- Presenting a united front against protectionism and unilateralism;
- Undertaking joint military exercises;
- Increasing the use of their own currencies in their growing cross-country trade, rather than the US dollar.
- Presenting a united front against protectionism and unilateralism;
- Undertaking joint military exercises;
- Increasing the use of their own currencies in their growing cross-country trade, rather than the US dollar.
It seems Trump’s trade war on China and sanctions on Russia (though I’m not opposed to the latter) have given Russia and China a common enemy.
How effectively can the rest of the world reign in the strategic ambitions, interference and unfair trade practices of two parties that are now cooperating, when our biggest ally is picking a fight with his own side?
Friday, 7 September 2018
Is it too late to prevent an Australian recession?
My newfound pessimism.
Until recently, I’d been quietly optimistic about Australia’s
future as we continue our transition away from the mining and resources boom. That’s
not to say there weren’t issues. The real economy had been sluggish for a while.
Housing markets got dangerously hot, especially Melbourne and Sydney. Australian
households are among the most indebted in the world. And wage growth still remains low despite economic
growth strengthening and unemployment falling towards 5%.
But I still had confidence. The RBA, APRA and ASIC had
effectively reigned in the property markets. And they did this with their
macro-prudential regulation and oversight. This meant the RBA didn’t have to raise
their own interest rates (which would have hurt the already sluggish real economy). Other sectors were
rising to take the place of the mining and resources sector, including education (Australia’s
third largest export). And the government had enacted its own fiscal stimulus
in the form of public infrastructure works, especially public transport.
All that was required was for wage growth to pick up again.
This would allow households to gradually pay down their debt levels without necessitating
a major correction. But time seems to be running out.
First, wage growth is still stubbornly low. And if
the US is any indication (4% unemployment and similarly slow wage growth), Australia
may still have a few years
before real wage growth emerges. And new information has revealed the Australian households’ savings
rate is now at a 6-year low. When that source of spending dries up, we’ll need
another.
Second, household debt may have reached a tipping
point. Not just because it is already so high. But because for many households,
it’s about to become a whole lot more expensive. One of the concerns of the
RBA, APRA and ASIC over the past few years has been the proliferation of
interest-only loans. Commercial banks gave a lot of mortgages that, for the first 5 or so years, didn’t require any of the principle to be paid. As the name suggests, only interest
needed to be paid. For financially savvy and ideally already-wealthy
individuals, this was a useful new source of financial flexibility.
Unfortunately, for many borrowers, it just delayed the inevitable realisation
that it was more than they could afford. And in 2019, 900,000 of these interest-only loans are due to expire. This will force the average interest-only
borrower to suddenly pay an extra $400 a month in principle. This potential
wave of defaults may not undermine the financial sector itself[1].
But the shock to household consumption and by extension, business investment,
could be significant.
Third, interest rates are rising around the world, driven
by the US. The Federal Reserve was already on a path towards normalising
interest rates. And the US government’s current spending spree – to the extent
it drives short term economic activity – is likely to accelerate this. The
additional debt the US government will have to issue will have the same impact
(more government bonds depresses their price and raises their yield – a key global
interest rate). And on top of the Fed’s cash rate, the Fed will also want to start
reducing the balance sheet they drastically expanded following the GFC. Again,
a sudden influx of these assets onto the market will depress their prices and
raise their yields. The RBA does have 1.5% worth of scope to drop our domestic
interest rates further (technically even more if they’re willing to consider
negative interest rates). But that is a lot of upward potential global pressure
to offset.
Fourth, any major economic downturn in Australia will
automatically worsen the federal budget. Income growth will slow or reverse,
causing government revenue to do the same. And outlays will expand as more
people require income and unemployment support. This is an ‘automatic stabiliser’
designed to stimulate the economy during a downturn and cool it during a boom.
Unfortunately, I’m concerned our conservative government may use that as an
excuse to tighten the budget further. This is the opposite of what is
needed during an economic downturn. And it’s especially unjustified given Australian
government debt is low by international standards and low relative to Australian
households. Their borrowing costs are also still low.
Slow wages, high debt, a sudden spike in local mortgage
costs, increasing pressure on international borrowing costs, and doubts
surrounding our government’s fiscal response – seems like the perfect recipe
for a downward spiral. And I haven’t even mentioned the potential for Australia
to get caught up in the US’s global trade war.
But this is not a “recession we have to have”. As I’ve written before, financial
crises – even Depression- or GFC-scale ones – can be managed without widespread
disaster and hardship. The Reserve Bank can provide the emergency liquidity and
(if necessary) the targeted bailouts to support the financial sector through
the initial panic[2].
Interest rates – both short term and long term – can be lowered, even into
negative territory. The Federal Government can take the opportunity (and
necessity) to borrow at these very low rates and enact even more significant
infrastructure investments. Targeted tax cuts are also an option. And once the
economy is back on solid footing (i.e. business, industry and households have
resumed as the main driving force) – but not before – debts can be paid down
and financial market regulation and oversight improved to avoid a future repeat
of such a crisis.
But this requires a lot of pieces in the right place at the
right time – and no small amount of luck. Hence my increasing pessimism.
[1]
Australian banks are quite well capitalised, thanks in part to additional
requirements placed on them by APRA in the last few years to hedge against
potential liquidity problems in the future.
[2]
Though as mentioned earlier, I don’t think the financial sector itself is in
significant systemic danger.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)